By Paul Goble
Research conducted in the North Caucasus
has shown that almost all conflicts in the region are in some way related to
disputes over land control or ownership. Studies on rural extremism also confirm
that the privatization of land into the hands of the rural population keeps
such disputes from becoming violent. Unfortunately, in the North Caucasus, and
among the Balkars of the Kabardino-Balkarian Republic (KBR) in particular, land
was privatized into the hands of elite officials rather than into those of the
peasants. As a result, a process that could have potentially eased ethnic
conflicts has had the exact opposite effect, according to Denis Sokolov, a
highly-regarded specialist on the region at the Russian Academy of Economics
and State Service (Kavpolit.com,
February 5).
In
his proactively titled article, “The Balkar Question—Import Substitution via
Revolution,” Sokolov argues that there are only two ways for the Balkars to
avoid descending into anarchy and violence: “a revolution from below” or “a
revolution from above.” Following the imposition of Western sanctions, he argues,
many assumed that the North Caucasus could contribute to Russian food supplies
and simultaneously reap the economic benefits. But “without institutional
reforms and […] without a resolution of the land issue,” it will be impossible to
boost the region’s economy or contribute to food supplies for the rest of
Russia.
When
government land was privatized in the 1990s, it was usually distributed to the
local elite (both criminal and otherwise), which was usually of Kabardinian
origin, rather than to those who could actually farm it (mainly ethnic Balkars).
In 2005, Arsen Kanokov became president of Kabardino-Balkaria with a promise to
change this. However, given the power of the elite and their strong hold on
property in rural areas, Kanokov was unable to keep his campaign promise. On
the contrary, the president’s initiative led to increased levels of banditry
and even cattle rustling, as rural workers tried to take back what they felt
was rightfully theirs.
The
struggle over land in KBR is, in effect, a struggle for power rather than for
property, although property is the marker of ethnicity and Islam remains the
most important tool for mobilization. Sokolov argues that in order to back out
of this dead end, the republic needs radical reform through either a “revolution
from below” or a “revolution from above.” The former would involve the peasants
revolting against the regime; the latter would occur if new leadership was willing
to sacrifice some of the elite’s interests in order to support those who can
actually farm the land, both for themselves and for the sake of the republic’s
economy.
Because
of their isolation from the “republic’s political machine”, which remains
dominated by the more numerous and elite Kabardinians, ethnic Balkars are
taking the lead in raising the land question and promoting the idea of a “revolution
from below.” Thus, if a revolution does erupt in the KBR, it will mostly likely
be led by the Balkars, and the Kabardinians will seek to present themselves as
the defenders of order when, in fact, they will simply aim to defend the status
quo.
A
revolution from above is unlikely because of Moscow’s focus on short-term
stability; and consequently, that makes a revolution from below more probable.
In such a scenario, the Turkic Balkars are likely to be the driving force in
KBR, even though they have received far less attention than the Kabardinians, a
branch of the Circassians, up to now.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.